A Profile for Killing

February 4th, 2008

Today’s news brings up an important question: are American and other military forces using profiling techniques in selecting targets for assassination?

Let’s speculate for a moment. Suppose you are a tactical commander for an occupying military force in some such place as Iraq or Gaza. You are locked in a struggle with a partisan militia, and you don’t have enough intelligence data to know who its members are. Your main weapon is aerial bombing; your main information source is aerial observation.

Begin by assuming that there is a probability that any randomly selected male between the ages of 16 and 40 is a militia fighter, say 10%. (Women may be fighters too, but their likelihood is much lower.) It is not in your interested to try to kill everyone in that demographic; you would give young men no incentive to not join the militia.

But what about groups of young men? Suppose that the probability of being in a militia rises with the number of military-age men who are seen meeting together. It might be 25% for groups of four, 50% for groups of six, and so on. Once a gathering reaches a certain size you determine that the risk of bombing non-fighters (type I error) is small enough that you should attack.

This model is too simple, of course. An actual profiling system would presumably include other dimensions (ethnic, geographic, time of day), but the general idea remains the same: if a gathering of men is given a high enough score you kill them. The result is that you eliminate a large number of those fighting against you, and you also accept the occasional public relations setback of bombing a wedding, a work detail, a militia unit made up of local collaborators.

I would like to see two things: the actual profiling methods employed by American, Israeli and similar forces (not a chance), and a public defense of the procedure by those who carry out or support it. Right now there is only silence and invisibility, but does anyone doubt that assassination-by-profile is standard operating procedure in modern anti-insurgency warfare?

The Market Panic in Perspective

January 21st, 2008

Does anyone else see the irony in the ongoing panic in global asset markets? Last week we feared global imbalances; this week we fear they may dissipate.

Don’t get me wrong — the last thing I want to see is global rebalancing by way of a massive US recession. But why are investors from Hong Kong to Frankfurt getting spooked? They are signaling that they don’t think their economies are decoupled from ours, and that a US downturn means the global buyer of last resort is putting away his credit cards. The US will cease to be the bottomless export market, and sellers everywhere will stumble.

Maybe so, but drastically curtailing the US import habit is a necessary part of rebalancing; it is not possible for US exports alone to do the job. So the contagion we’re seeing demonstrates that the current imbalances have become addictive on all sides. (OK, rebalancing via recession lacks a terms of trade sweetener, but is that what the markets are freaking about?)

Nonsense on Imported Stilts

January 16th, 2008

Econ bloggers have really missed the point about Landsburg’s free trade screed. The estimable Dani notwithstanding, the issue isn’t ultimately ethics or even procedural fairness. The problem is that doctrinaire economists understand less about trade than the average person with no academic training in the subject.

Ordinary people in many parts of the world, and not just in the US, worry about trade because they are afraid that jobs lost to imports will not be counterbalanced by jobs gained through exports. They worry that there will be fewer economic opportunities for them and their children. They worry that their wages or working conditions will be pushed downward through competition with even more vulnerable, desperate workers in other countries. They are right to worry about these things. Such miseries are not destined to happen, but they cannot be ruled out either.

Except in standard economic models which begin with the assumption that increases in imports automatically call forth equally valued increases in exports. If trade balances on the margin we live in the happy world of comparative advantage, and it is indeed true, as Landsburg says, that “when American jobs are outsourced, Americans as a group are net winners.” But the assumption that trade balances at the margin is simply a modeling convenience, something that enables Landsburg to regale his students with blackboards full of elegant diagrams and equations. It is not grounded in real experience, and especially not the experience of the US economy since the 1970s.

You have to be very well trained in economics and have high-level skills to make such a brain-dead assumption and not even know you’ve made it. Then you don’t have to give serious consideration to counterarguments because, hey, why pay any attention to the fallacies of economic illiterates and mathphobes?

But let’s get specific. Here’s how Landsburg illustrates his claim that international trade makes us better off: “I doubt there’s a human being on earth who hasn’t benefited from the opportunity to trade freely with his neighbors. Imagine what your life would be like if you had to grow your own food, make your own clothes and rely on your grandmother’s home remedies for health care.”

Notice a problem here? Landsburg assumes that there is no difference between trade within an economy and international trade. (To be more precise, the only difference is that governments interfere more often with trade across national borders.) Worse, he accuses anyone who recognizes the difference of woolly thinking, based of course on his assumption that there is no difference.

This is why the French students complained about autistic economics.

For what it’s worth, my view is that we as a society ought to provide opportunities for as many of us as possible to have a satisfying livelihood. If a community is down and out we should step in and do what we can whether or not trade played a role in creating the problem. We should create rules for international trade that minimize downward pressure on wage, environmental and social standards and that limit dangerous imbalances. These ideas are fairly widespread among the general population, and if economists think really creatively they might just be able to rise to the same level.

The Rationality Divide in Politics?

January 3rd, 2008

According to Leonhardt in yesterday’s New York Times, the fault line between Clinton and Obama runs through the rationality postulate. Hilary’s citizenry is rational and responds to precisely calibrated market incentives; Barack’s is guided by impulse and habit and can only be moved by big policy objects in bright colors with thick borders. Is this the revolution in economics we’ve been hearing about?

Leonhardt locates the Obama/Goolsbee strategy in the rise of behavioral economics, an approach that replaces robotic rationality with a psychologically realistic characterization of real-world decision-making. In particular, he is drawing on the field of behavioral law and economics, which emphasizes commonplace cognitive “biases” that prevent people from acting consistently in their own interests. Examples include “availability bias” (attributing greater-than-actual probability to outcomes that are vivid or widely publicized), “status quo bias” (resistance to switching from A to B, or if starting with B, from B to A) and the inability to cope with high levels of complexity (such as public benefits few apply for because the forms are too complicated).

With this view of human fallibility, it is not surprising that practitioners of this sort of economic thinking incline to paternalism. The non-biased minority with impeccable cognitive skills (you know who you are) must take it on themselves to guide their less capable brethren toward more rational choices. I exaggerate, but not too much, as those who have delved into this literature will recognize. Yes, there is elitism in the traditional incentive-based approach too, but it is at least honest and transparent in its methods. The flagship policy innovation of the behavior-wonks, making participation in private savings plans the default option, so that workers would have to choose to opt out (rather than making no savings the default and asking them to opt in), combines the we-know-what’s-best-for-you of the incentive school with a kind of tawdry manipulation. Of course, it may also work better.

But loyal readers of this blog should be aware that behavioral economics is much larger than its portrayal by Leonardt. For one thing, much research now focuses on the differences in behavioral patterns across the population. Rather than fixing on the central tendency, attention has shifted to the dispersion. What this will mean for policy is not clear at this point, but it has to lead to greater diversification and decentralization of the means and ends, don’t you think?

Another important departure concerns the emergence, reproduction and evolution of social norms governing economic (and other) behavior. Many, myself included, think this has enormous potential for changing how we think about politics and human well-being. It reintroduces cultural factors that have been banished from proper economics for generations, not least of which are the gender norms emphasized by feminist economists. And what about the effect that changes in governmental policies and business practices have on the norms governing income distribution? We have begun to see empirical work in this area and it is a safe prediction that we’ll see a lot more.

I hate writing these vague, sweeping posts, but it would take much more than a few paragraphs to properly document the upsurge in behavioral research. The point for now is: the policy space spanned by Clinton and Obama is minuscule compared to the opportunities for new thinking in economics that already exist.

An Earful on the Science and Policy of Risk

December 26th, 2007

The New York Times reports that Europe is gradually approaching the point of decision on whether to allow genetically modified corn. Because of WTO rules on such things, the EU is required to base its policy on “science” if it want to keep out mutant corn from the US. This reflects a deep, deep misunderstanding of what science can contribute to policy.

Let’s start with the basics. There are two sorts of error we can make in this uncertain world, Type I (the risk of believing something to be the case when it is not) and Type II (the risk of not believing something to be the case when it is). Science is, among other things, a human enterprise organized around the systematic minimization of Type I error. Experimental protocols are about this, and so are the conventions we follow in determining statistical significance. This obsession comes at the cost of permitting greater Type II error, but that’s OK. Science operates on the basis of a vast division of labor, where each scientist’s work depends on the reliability of the methods and results carried over from what others have done. One false conclusion, if not noticed in time, could invalidate the efforts of an entire research community. This is why a serious Type I error is a potential career ender, whereas an avoidable Type II glitch simply diminishes a researcher’s list of accomplishments.

This single-minded insistence on avoiding Type I error is the reason why science is the one truly progressive human activity. Today’s science is better than yesterday’s, and tomorrow’s will be better than today. You can’t say this about poetry or politics.

(It is also, in the end, why economics is not a “real” science: it is no big deal for an economist to claim something to be true and to later discover that it isn’t.)

Policy, on the other hand, has to take Type II error as seriously as Type I. Take the Bt corn case before the EU, for example. It is a problem if regulators falsely think Bt corn is dangerous and ban it, but it is also a problem if they falsely think it is not dangerous and allow it to be used. A reasonable first cut is the standard cost-benefit approach: value each sort of error in terms of its cost function. Thus the cost of banning Bt corn is the probability of Type I error (falsely believing it to be harmful) times the economic cost of not taking advantage of this technology, whereas the cost of not banning it is the probability of Type II error times the cost of the damage it would do in that case. You go for the lowest cost option.

(There is an even better approach, as I argued here, based on the fullest possible utilization of information.)

The difference should be obvious. Science is radically asymmetric in the way it treats uncertainty: avoiding a false positive is everything. Policy is more balanced: failure to see is potentially as harmful as seeing what isn’t there. If you happen to be the sort of person, as I am, who thinks environmental risks are particularly important to avoid, you might tilt the policy calculus on issues like Bt corn toward less Type II error, even at the expense of more Type I.

Science has one job to do. Policy has another. They follow different rules.

CGE: Is There a Defense?

December 20th, 2007

I’ve been asked to review an article using computable general equilibrium (CGE) methodology. I’m likely to decline, but before I do I want to ask the vast universe that follows this blog: is there any defense against the argument that CGE and its offspring (DSGE) are simply bad economics?

There are two arguments actually:

1. CGE is an attempt to implement empirically a model that has been blown away theoretically. For 30 years we have known in precise terms why representative agent GE models are hogwash. We also know that the conditions for unique solutions are impossibly restrictive. Finally, while we have models that can translate modern, post-utility understanding of economic behavior into functional form, to do this throughout an economy, in every nook and sector, would be a gargantuan, and probably pointless, project. To put it bluntly, CGE modelers take as their starting point refuted theory.

2. CGE is false empiricism. It claims to generate results based on real-world data, but testing is nil, and I mean nil. Is there any literature out there I have missed in which past models are examined retrospectively against actual economic outcomes? If not, where is the falsifiability?

I will wait to send my rejection email. Maybe one of you can convince me that it is worth a few hours of my time to promote “better” CGE work.

Further Thoughts on Populism, With Application to Criticisms of Edwards’ Fancy Digs

December 20th, 2007

Inspired by Barkley, I have more to say about populism. In a nutshell, the word has multiple connotations, and political opinion-molders manipulate the ambiguities for their own purposes. Let’s disentangle and shed some light.

I think the Wikipedia entry is right in identifying “the people” in populist thought as counterposed to an elite that insults and oppresses them. But what do populists propose as the remedy?

Long ago, in an article for a journal with no web presence and therefore no linkability, I wrote that there are three ways that political movements can claim to be democratic. (1) They can claim that their leading members are “of the people”, that they can be trusted to represent the majority because, by birth and life circumstances, they are part of it. I called this agent-based publicness. (2) They can claim that their programs would benefit the interests of the majority. This is akin to the utilitarianism of mainstream economics, particularly if metrics, such as median income, are used to take distribution into account. I called this interest-based publicness. (3) They can promote programs or institutions that expand the direct role of the majority in deliberation and decision-making in the public sphere: transparency, participation, etc. I called this process-based publicness.

In my view, all three have a role to play, and all of them have blind spots that need to be recognized and offset. What interests me right now is not the question of what mix would be best in general or in the US in 2008, but how these different approaches are confused in our current political discourse.

First, all three can be expressions of populism if they are presented as solutions to the dispossession of the people by the elites.

And what do they look like today?

Agent-based populism: A candidate has a personal style, including a method of speaking, that shows he or she is “like us”. This could mean anything from avoiding complicated academic language to making references to pop music, to going to NASCAR races (OK, not in 2008 any more) or on hunting trips. It can also mean being multi-racial if “the people” are seen as multi-racial. It depends, obviously, on who “we” are. Mike Huckabee’s populism is, as far as I can tell, almost entirely of this sort. South of where I normally sit (in an office in the US), one of the chief populist claims for Hugo Chavez and Evo Morales is that they really understand the poor, nonwhite majority because this is their heritage too.

Interest-based populism: Every reader of this blog knows that America has reached new depths of economic inequality under Reagan-Bush-Clinton-Bush. An interest-based populist in this context should be someone like Edwards who campaigns on this reality and proposes policies on the grounds that they would reverse it. (Whether those policies are adequate to the job is another matter.) It is possible, however, for someone to argue that the true interests of the people are not economic but cultural, the preservation of their prejudices, taboos, etc. This opens the door to populists like George Wallace or, today, Lou Dobbs—to take an example from the media.

Process-based populism: I make a big deal of this possibility because I believe it has much more to offer than it is given credit for, but I have to admit that it is barely visible on the current political landscape. A candidate could take up this mantle by championing democratic social movements, unions and greater direct public participation in government. Civil liberties largely fall within this framework as well, as they provide the foundation for popular activism against the state. There is much discussion of how to expand the capacity and role of civil society elsewhere—in Latin America and the EU especially—but hardly any in the US. Kucinich gives us a small taste of this, when we can find him, and Obama (very) obliquely hints at it.

So this brings us to the use of “populism” as a pejorative, and specifically as it pertains to Edwards. Those who say he is a false populist because he enjoys an upscale lifestyle are relying on populism #1: he is not truly of the people. But he could live in bourgeois luxury of the most extreme sort and still deliver on populism #2. Think FDR.

A second critique of populism goes directly at #2, I believe. It is argued that the immediate interests of the downtrodden are in conflict with sound economic policy. The poor want handouts, but this would bludgeon the budget, wipe out incentives for investment, etc. By appealing too openly to the multitudes, someone like Edwards is seen as being at risk of becoming beholden to their short-sighted demands. Here the underlying presumption is that the poor have little understanding of their long-term interests and are prone to being bought off. Indeed, there is a cynical form of populism, much practiced in Latin America, in which a few highly publicized giveaways are used to win support, while fundamental policies continue to favor the rich.

My judgment, for now, is that Edwards is not guilty of this second sin.

What we mostly lack, I think, is the third dimension, empowerment. Is it accidental that it is historically linked to socialism?

Who is a "Populist"?

December 19th, 2007

In recent election cycles the term “populist” has been applied to such varied figures as John Edwards, Mike Huckabee, Patrick Buchanan, and Ross Perot, arguably sharing a sort of economic nationalism for the poor. Originating in anti-aristocratic agrarian movements in Europe, especially the Russian Narodniki of the late 1800s, the movement in the US attempted to encompass the urban working class as well, as symbolized by the rural Scarecrow marching along with the urban Tin Woodman on the Yellow Brick Road to defeat the Wicked Witch of the East, with populist heroine Dorothy and the Cowardly Lion stand-in for fundamentalist and anti-imperialist populist William Jennings Bryan, he of the “Cross of Gold” speech, in Baum’s populist fantasy novel. The movement would be partly absorbed by the later Progressive and New Deal movements.

The movement has always had a deep divide, with race the central issue. So, on the one hand we have the progressive wing, symbolized by the remnant Democratic-Farmer-Labor Party of Minnesota and the presidential candidacy in 1948 of FDR’s former Ag Secretary, Henry Wallace for the Progressive Party. On the other, in the Deep South, we got “Pitchfork” Ben Tillman in South Carolina, whose follower, Strom Thurmond, would run as the “Dixiecrat” in the 1948 presidential campaign. Today, this divide most clearly shows up in the struggle over immigration.

Credit Crunch and Sudden Stop: Can We Avoid a Perfect Financial Storm?

December 12th, 2007

Credit markets are all a-jitter again. No one knows how many assets will be nonperforming, which ones they will be, how much total value is at stake. We also know that there has a been a sudden stop, a complete cessation of net long-term private capital inflows to the US; nearly all of the financing burden of the US current account deficit has to be shouldered by central banks and sovereign wealth funds. These two events are related.

It is US debt, mortgage items but perhaps not only, whose quality is in doubt. This is why there is little appetite for such goodies among private investors. But if enough liquidity is pumped in to dissuade investors from wholesale dumping, and if the CB’s continue to do what it takes to keep the dollar afloat, we may continue to muddle through.

The risk is that the two dangers will interact. The Fed and its partners can support asset values by buying into these markets, as they have indicated they will. But if for any reason this effort falls short, it is possible that default risk and currency risk could spiral upward in tandem. Fear of default could push private capital flows into the red; this would ramp up the pressure on the dollar, increasing currency risk, and so on. It is not beyond the realm of the possible that this nasty synergy could erupt within the time frame of a few hours or even minutes. It would be sudden and unexpected: one morning you could go online to scan the headlines and find out we were already in the thick of it.

I’m not saying that a crisis is inevitable, but I’m not saying it can’t happen either.

Fatal Truck Crashes: A Publishing Opportunity for Economists

December 7th, 2007

From the Pump Handle comes this. I’m too busy to turn these findings into an economics journal article, but I’ll tell you how to do it so you can pad your own CV.


First you need a theoretical model. You can show that, with a fixed salary and positive barriers to mobility (for instance in a searching/matching model of the labor market), truck drivers are unable to optimize on their relative preferences for money income and safety. This welfare loss can be overcome by the payment of piece rates. Now each truck driver can locate his or her own personal optimum in wage/risk space. (We abstract from the welfare benefits/costs of the direct effects of amphetamine use.) But there is also a potential externality, in that other drivers or pedestrians may be killed or maimed in truck accidents. The solution is a nonlinear wage schedule that reduces effective hourly pay by the expected cost of the externality according to increasing effect of work hours on accident rates. If you want to get even fancier, you could throw in the principal-agent dimension and put your solution in the context of optimal contract theory.

For the empirical section you would need the raw trucker data. It would be very simple, really a spreadsheet exercise, to impute the marginal value of an extra hour’s work from the piece rate schedule, and to calculate the marginal increase in the probability of a fatal accident. From this you could determine the VSL (value of a statistical life). The required level of analytical foggery could be achieved by testing for baseline effects, income and substitution effects, lots of stuff.

One thing that would not go into the article would be the observation that all of the above smiles on personnel practices that kill truckers.

It’s really a shame that they don’t let me supervise Ph.D. theses.

Unsolicited Advice for the Bali Brigades

December 3rd, 2007

The eco-elite have descended on Bali to devise a successor regime to the Kyoto Protocol. I think most of them are asking the wrong questions and are likely to come up with the wrong answers.

To begin with, we should be clear on what the limitations of Kyoto are. They are not primarily the weak targets that were set for carbon reduction, nor were they the forbearance shown to developing countries. Why not?

The targets proved not to matter because they have not been met. In fact, there is no way at present to force a country to act decisively on curbing greenhouse gases, so discussion of specific targets is a sideshow. In any case, no country should pull back from taking aggressive action because an international treaty sets the bar several notches lower.

For the same reason, it was never a problem that Kyoto exempted low income countries from the expectations put on the industrialized world. Aside from the question of equity – climate change is driven by accumulated emissions, most of which came from us and not them – there is no way to force a country like China or India to make its development conditional on reaching carbon goals.

The one thing Kyoto did that “worked” shouldn’t have, carbon offsets. The evidence shows that much of the offsets actually offset nothing at all: they are fictitious carbon reductions. And others take money to mitigate one environmental hazard by creating another, like tree plantations that replace living forests.

So the first thing an enlightened eco-diplomat in Bali should understand is that Kyoto should not be fixed; it should be scrapped. I appreciate its symbolic value, but surely the time for symbolism is past.

What to do then? The starting point for reasonable negotiation is the awareness that the majority of the world’s people will be direct financial beneficiaries of controlling climate change, if the job is done properly. Any country that sets up a system of carbon permits, auctions them off and rebates the money to its citizens on a per capita basis will find that most will come out ahead. This is because climate-bashing consumption is disproportionately done by the rich. Make them pay for it, and distribute the proceeds equally; the lower- and middle-consumption majority will get back more than they pay in. To put it another way, societies have been giving away their crucial environmental resources, like the atmosphere in its role as a waste sink, for free to anyone who wants to take them. Charging a price puts money in the pockets of the owners – us.

Implication: we don’t need a global treaty for countries to set up serious carbon emission controls. That’s not what Bali should be about.

What it can do are two things. First, by far the most efficient point at which to control carbon is where it enters the economy, as oil, coal or gas at the mine or wellhead. This is far less complicated than trying to track it down in its myriad uses, and it leaves the fewest loopholes. For any individual country this will mean requiring permits to bring fossil fuels across the border. Negotiators of a new international framework can work to standardize these permits, so that their markets can be international. This would minimize disruption to cross-border economic life. (I’m a rootless cosmopolitan and favor this sort of thing.)

The most important topic to discuss, however, is how to insulate national economies from the possibility that carbon control could raise domestic costs of production, hurting domestic producers in international markets. (Yes, I know the argument from trade theory that says this is not a problem, and no, I don’t believe it.) It is becoming clear that this will have to take the form of carbon adjustment tariffs (CAT’s), something I weighed in on a few posts back. I think there is a real risk that lobbyists would swarm all over the process of deciding how large a tariff is needed to offset carbon cost differences, and that an internationally negotiated schedule would have more integrity. That, more than anything else, is what Bali should be about, setting up a framework for negotiating such tariff schedules, so that each country can decide for itself how aggressive to be in carbon policy without worrying about getting too far out front.

What Bali should not do is convey to anyone anywhere that local or national action has to wait until a worldwide consensus has been reached.

Uh Oh

November 28th, 2007

This is serious:

The blue stuff is private sector financing of the US current account deficit; the red stuff is life support from foreign central banks and SIV’s (sovereign investment funds). Brad Setser points out, as he has from the beginning of his blog, that official flows (red) are greatly underestimated; by arithmetic logic they have to make up the difference between private flows and the current account.

But the point is clear: if the US were any other country (i.e. too big to fail), we would be in the grips of an economic crisis at this very moment. Foreign exchange would freeze up, essential goods would be unavailable, mass layoffs would ripple across the land, while the dollar would sink like a stone. This would be Mexico 1994, Argentina 2001.

But it’s not, at least not right now. By the grace of central bankers and oil fund managers we in the US get to sip our latte (or in my case Darjeeling) and muse on this question in tranquility. But the dollar keeps going down, and the governments that prop us up are taking really big losses. The talk now is of Wiley E. Coyote and Hyman Minsky.

OK, this is scary, but those of us who have followed the situation have been scared for years, and yet the crisis still hasn’t come. Maybe this is another false alarm. We have been in bailout mode for a long, long time.

Still, the risk of a rupture is real. My advice: progressive people need to start thinking systematically about the political environment we are likely to find ourselves in if all hell breaks loose. What narratives, based in reality or fantasy, will make sense of this catastrophe for the general public? Who will step forward to manage the crisis? How can we minimize the risk of an authoritarian surge?

And you think you’re paranoid?

In the Long Run We’re All Hung Over from the Short Run

November 12th, 2007

One of fundamentals of contemporary economic wisdom is that short run fluctuations only affect short run output; in the long run it’s all about growth. Textbooks have dropped their chapters on business cycles and replaced them with fancy growth models. The short run is for speculators; the long run is for serious policy analysts. But what if it’s all wrong?

A recent paper by Cerra and Saxena, two economists at the Bank for International Settlements, argues that the economic costs of recessions and more serious crises tend to be permanent. According to their analysis, post-recession recovery does not generally return an economy to its pre-recession growth trend, but shifts the trend line down a notch. That is, periods of negative growth are not usually followed by periods of above-trend growth. Poor countries may be poor not because their growth rates during healthy periods are lower, but because they have more and deeper disruptions.

I am not in position to adjudicate, except to notice (1) most economists simply assume that recovery returns an economy to trend, (2) the issue is of enormous importance, and (3) if Cerra and Saxena are right, we need to rewrite the macro textbooks (again).

UPDATE: DeLong endorses the view that short run effects don’t last:

Which side am I on? I tell my undergraduates:

At a time horizon of 0-3 years, be a Keynesian: the most important things are the fluctuations in unemployment, in real demand, and in capacity utilization.

At a time horizon of 3-8 years, be a demand-side monetarist: you can assume (provisionally) that fluctuations in employment, real demand, and capacity utilization die out; the most important things are the fluctuations in the composition of real demand (investment vs. consumption vs. government vs. net exports) and in inflation- and deflation-causing nominal demand assuming (provisionally) stable growth of the economy’s productive capacity.

At a time horizon of 8 years or greater, be a sane supply-sider: the most important things are the processes of investment in physical, human, and organizational capital that raise the economy’s productive capacity

Back to School on Exchange Rates

November 10th, 2007

Menzie Chinn has done us all a service with his review of recent exchange rate theory, which I also skimmed in this. I was particularly intrigued by his reference to Frydman and Goldberg’s “Imperfect Knowledge Economics” approach. I read their article but not their book, and at the risk of thereby embarrassing myself offer these thoughts.

1. F&G are certainly right that a single model should not be expected to explain xrate movements over long periods of time because the market determinants are changing. This fits to a Kuhnian view: there are periods of “normal” trading, where movements respond predictably to economic news, and paradigm shifts—discontinuities in trading behavior.

2. PPP is a weak attractor at best. This is because the vast majority of transactions in international markets concern stocks, not flows. Forex markets are more like stamp or coin markets than markets in toothpaste, but PPP is based on the toothpaste template. Self-fulfilling prophecies can persist until the effects of currency misalignment are so disruptive that macro events force a correction; arbitrage doesn’t regulate. Any intermediate xrate would appear to be a statistical attractor due to mean reversion; is there any evidence that PPP outperforms other values in that respect?

3. F&G frame their argument in terms of forecasting, which on a practical level is certainly the test. The larger question, however, is whether their approach, or any of the alternatives, is consistent with the role assigned to xrates in micro models of international trade. This was the issue I raised in Challenge. The general answer, I still think, is that they don’t. F&G in particular present a view that, in theory, cannot be reconciled with strict comparative advantage. If a shifting bundle of macro fundamentals determine xrates, and if their weights change from one period to the next, how then can international prices be relied on to settle at levels that balance trade at the margin?

F&G end with the habitual sop toward trade orthodoxy, continuing the Hayekian tradition of deep insight into the process of markets combined with an inability or unwillingness to see that the normative view of markets has been eviscerated.

Strike-Bike Stricken

November 5th, 2007

On November 1, Strike-Bike was locked out. The Nordhausen factory had been occupied by its workers since July 10, producing over 1800 bicycles. (You could order them in any color you want as long as it was red.) Now the court has taken over and the future of the operation is in doubt.

It’s always good when workers take an initiative, but the long term prospects were hardly rosy. This is one more instance in which a worker takeover occurred in response to the failure of capitalist owners, “lemon self-management” so to speak. There was self-exploitation as well: workers paid themselves just 10 euros an hour in their last-ditch attempt to keep the business going.

For a real test of self-organized production there has to be a level playing field: profits to be had by both owners and workers. And the goal would not be (only) to stave off insolvency, but to transform products and production methods for a better world.

The CAT* is out of the Bag

November 2nd, 2007

*That’s Carbon Adjustment Tariff to you. It’s coming, probably, and here are some ideas for what form it should take.

The basic idea is simple: any country that gets serious about controlling carbon emissions will raise the price of the stuff, directly or indirectly. Because carbon inputs are important in many other goods and services, they will raise those prices too. If some countries take action on climate change and others don’t this will lead to distortions in global markets. Otherwise well-meaning governments might refrain from action, fearing the competitive effects. If the elasticities are particularly unfavorable, it is even possible that stringent regulation in one country could lead to an exodus of industry to places where carbon burns freely, resulting in an overall increase in global emissions.

So put a tariff on goods to offset price differences attributable to different carbon regimes. There isn’t an accepted name for the idea yet, so let’s call it a carbon adjustment tariff. The idea can be found in Warner-Lieberman and has been broached by heads of state in Paris and Berlin. It is difficult to see how individual countries can take the lead without it.

Good ideas can have bad consequences unless they are thought through, however. Here are three principles that ought to govern a CAT you could love.

1. A tariff schedule should be insulated as far as possible from self-interested manipulation. In a better world it would be the product of a representative and accountable global agency. In the shabby one we live in it should at least be the joint product of a subset of countries, rich and developing, that are willing to take some initiative.

2. All the money collected under such a tariff—repeat, all the money—should be returned in some fashion to the countries of origin, to finance green investment. Yes, I know a lot of this cash will be misspent, but it would be misspent in the collecting country too. The CAT must not become another means to suck scarce resources from South to North.

3. Some or all of the revenues should be held in escrow, pending the agreement of the trading partner to enter a “contract and converge” system under which it will approach a common per capita carbon emissions target. This money can sweeten a deal that should be made on its own merits.

It bears repeating: policies to forestall global warming are not only environmental policies. If they take their job seriously, they will have profound effects on national and global economies. They should be designed to be economically progressive and sustainable.

Conduitry: A Blast from the Past?

October 16th, 2007

It appears that the conduit consortium is simply an extra layer of securitization. It reminds me of the way the lender of last resort function was implemented, sort of, with several noticeable failures, in the era preceding the creation of the Fed. It has the potential to further concentrate risk, like an Army Corps flood control project that can withstand a category 3 but not 4 storm—if there are any buyers.

From an equity standpoint, I think James Hamilton has it right:

In my opinion, part of what created the current problem was the perception that participants were too big and too many to fail. If the government won’t let Citigroup fail, could it allow a superconduit to go down?

I am skeptical of any claims for a feel-good, this-will-solve-all-the-problems fix. The reality is that someone must absorb a huge capital loss. The question we should be asking from the point of view of public policy is, Who should that someone be?

My answer is: the shareholders of Citigroup.

Savings: The Consequence, not the Cause, of Current Account Imbalances

October 15th, 2007

You write stuff and hope people read it. Clearly the recent discussion on this blog and elsewhere of whether there is a savings glut over there or a savings shortage over here ignores completely the argument I made this year in Challenge. Was my case really that weak?

The Obama Carbon Plan

October 9th, 2007

2008 will be the year America debates climate change policy, hopefully without descending completely into election-year inanity. 2009 will be the year we get a policy. For an issue of this magnitude, that’s a fairly short time frame, so every turn of events counts.

Today Barack Obama has gone on record with his own approach. By my reckoning he got almost everything right, but there’s one huge missing piece. He is right on:

• setting a serious target: an 80% reduction in emissions by 2050 is the minimum we should aim for, if we take the scientific evidence seriously. We can get there only by starting soon and staying on course.

• capping carbon emissions: a cap is necessary if we are going to try to live within ecological limits, and it is far preferable to a carbon tax, as I’ve argued earlier on this august site.

• auctioning the permits: as Obama said, letting the cows out of the Barnes, “Businesses don’t own the sky, the public does…”

• rejecting offsets: he doesn’t even mention them.

• investing in a non-carbon future: we need basic R&D, infrastructure and other initiatives to turn our economy around.

The only element that’s lacking is a commitment to rebating most of the auction revenues back to the people on a per capita basis. Economically, this is necessary to protect real incomes and avoid a dangerous contraction of consumer demand. (The higher energy prices we will be paying under any reasonable cap will be in the hundreds of billions of dollars.) Politically, it is necessary to win support for tough limits on carbon emissions. After all, if it is true that we own the sky, we should share in the income it generates. Finally, a per capita rebate would constitute the most progressive income redistribution program since the New Deal, a big consideration at a time of spiraling inequality.

So how do you finance those green investments if you give the money back? Answer: by ending pork barrel subsidies to the nuclear and fossil fuel mafias ($24B give or take a few) and rethinking national security, for starters. NB: if rebating the auction proceeds on an equal share basis is highly progressive, withholding a big chunk of it for other uses is highly regressive. Finance public investment out of taxes.